CPC(M-L) HOME TML Daily Archive Le Marxiste-Léniniste quotidien

November 30, 2010 - No. 205

Time to Rebuild Stelco


Picket line of locked out Hamilton steelworkers and supporters, November 19, 2010.

Time to Rebuild Stelco - Information Update, Local 1005 USW

British Columbia
Taseko Mines Open Pit Gold Mine Rejected
Brief Review of BC Mining

Discussion on Nation-Building -- The Necessity to Restrict Monopoly Right
Part Three: How the Problem of Prices of Production Poses Itself - Workers' Centre of CPC(M-L)


Time to Rebuild Stelco

U.S. Steel's lockout of 900 Hamilton steelworkers is an attempt to blackmail the union into selling out 9,000 pensioners and any new hires. It is also very destructive to the community.

In his letter to the Hamilton Spectator November 7, 2010, Hamilton resident Robert H. Thompson, former treasurer for Stelco, Inc. who retired in 2006 after 31 years in finance positions with Stelco, pointed out: "The closing of this facility's production will mean the end of hundreds of millions of dollars in raw material flowing through Hamilton's port; it will mean the loss of salaries and wages in excess of $100 million annually; it will also mean the loss of millions of dollars in property taxes and utility purchases which will have to be made up by others in Hamilton; and it will mean the loss of hundreds of millions of dollars in purchased goods and services from local suppliers throughout the community. Some of these local suppliers of goods and services will not survive without the steel plant, and as a consequence, there will be jobs besides those lost at U.S. Steel.... The economic fallout in Hamilton from this plant's closure will be serious and long lasting. This city can ill afford the loss of $1 billion in economic activity and the permanent loss of high-paying industrial jobs.... The risk for Hamilton is that even if U.S. Steel is successful in securing these concessions from 1005, there is no guarantee that Hamilton Works will ever reopen."


Hamilton, November 19, 2010

In the opinion of Local 1005, all of this raises the serious issue of the necessity to rebuild Stelco as an integrated steel producer. The dismantling and stripping of assets away from Stelco began under the influence of neoliberal globalization. This has to be reversed with nation-building.

U.S. Steel has proven itself unwilling to be a participant in Canadian nation-building as it has its own "U.S. First" agenda of concentrating manufacturing in the United States, taking over steel markets in Canada and eliminating steel competition in this country. U.S. Steel even admits in a submission to the Federal Court that it closed Stelco mills in Hamilton and Lake Erie to manipulate steel prices in North America for its own and other global producers' narrow benefit. Price manipulation is still a crime and so are violations of the Investment Canada Act. U.S. Steel admits to both. Such a rogue should not have control of a vital part of a key sector of the Canadian economy. Obviously, with the shutdowns and lockouts at Stelco, U.S. Steel is not a factor for nation-building. Neoliberal globalization for U.S. Steel means wrecking manufacturing in Canada, destroying the competition and securing a global market base.

The wrecking and dismantling of Stelco right from the beginning was a crime against the well-being and economic security of Canadians in which our community is most affected. Governments at the federal and provincial levels should have seen integrated Stelco as a national treasure and defended it and prosecuted all those who schemed to profit from its destruction. But they let it happen and are now standing idly by claiming it is U.S. Steel's right to do as it pleases.

U.S. Steel is so corrupt it is capable of saying and doing anything to further its empire-building. Why do our governments allow it to continue attacking us? Shame on them.

It is not too late to reverse the wrecking but the federal and provincial governments must be held responsible because they are the only force strong enough to enforce the survival and growth of this necessary manufacturing facility as a fortress of Canadian self-reliance, prosperity, security and economic well- being.

Keep Stelco Producing!

(Information Update, #39, November 29, 2010, www.uswa1005.ca)

Return to top


British Columbia

Taseko Mines Open Pit Gold Mine Rejected


Tsilhqot'in Aboriginal Nation and supporters demonstrate outside Taseko Mines' Annual General Meeting,
Vancouver, June 16, 2010. (RAVEN)

The federal Cabinet November 2 rejected Taseko Mines' proposed open pit gold-copper mine located 125-km southwest of Williams Lake, BC in the traditional unceded territory of the Tsilhqot'in Aboriginal Nation. This reckless proposal, fiercely opposed by the Tsilhqot'in people, was a by-product in part of the high price of gold, which has spawned an imperialist "gold fever" scramble throughout the world.

The Taseko Mines' proposal was particularly irrational, calling for the destruction of Teztan Biny (Fish Lake), Y'anah Biny (Little Fish Lake) and portions of Teztan Yeqox (Fish Creek). The portions of this crucial watershed to be destroyed, which flow to the Dasiqox (Taseko River), were designated as tailings (mine waste) impoundment areas, which would poison and kill fish and other life forms. Ironically, a federal Cabinet order allowing mining companies to circumvent the Fisheries Act and turn lakes into "tailings dumps" instead of building safe impoundment areas gave Taseko Mines a "legal" financial incentive for its socially irresponsible proposal.

The mine was broadly opposed by not only the Tsilhqot'in National Government and its allies but also many from the nearby community of Williams Lake and throughout BC. However, workers and businesspeople from the region were subjected to enormous pressure to support the project particularly in the face of the forestry crisis, as the development was loudly hailed as bringing "prosperity" for approximately twenty years.

Xeni Gwet'in Chief Marilyn Baptise of the Tsilhqot'in Nation said, "According to reports, the company spent $100 million pursuing this mine despite it being made clear since the beginning that neither our First Nations nor the federal government could accept this proposal. That money, the tax dollars wasted by the Province to promote this doomed proposal, and the scarce resources that First Nations were forced to use to defend against it could have been far better spent creating real economic opportunities and jobs. It is time to put an end to this waste and futility."

The Liberal Party in power in BC approved and promoted the mine proposal even though a review panel of the federal Ministry of Environment denounced it saying, "The Project would result in significant adverse environmental effects on fish and fish habitat, on navigation, on the current use of lands and resources for traditional purposes by First Nations and on cultural heritage, and on certain potential or established Aboriginal rights or title."


Vancouver, June 16, 2010 (RAVEN)

Tsilhqot'in National Government (TNG) Tribal Chair Chief Joe Alphonse said, "Taseko's proposal is dead and any variation that involves Fish Lake and its environs are non starters. If we want jobs and economic opportunity, we need to move on and find ways to work together to identify projects that can work... First Nations also want good jobs for our people and a future for our children and we want them to prosper, but we do not want to destroy our environment, values and future generations to achieve this... If we are to identify and work on projects that will stand the test of existing Aboriginal rights, future determinations of Aboriginal title in BC, and environmental responsibility, then we all need to work together on land use planning, decision sharing, reforming the online staking system, and creating a credible and valid environmental assessment process."

TML congratulates the TNG and Tsilhqot'in people for their courageous struggle against this dreadful project and its political backers in the BC government. TML also notes that even though workers in the Williams Lake area came under tremendous pressure to "get behind" this "prosperity" project, no great groundswell of support ever materialized, especially as the destructive details began to emerge and widespread discussion took place throughout the province led by the Tsilhqot'in people.

To combat the power and control of the mining monopolies and their narrow interests, a Workers' Opposition needs to coalesce around its own perspective and alternative program for sovereign economic development based on self-reliance, the needs of the people and general interests of society. Allowing the monopolies to dictate and control the economy is at the root of the economic problems faced by the people and Aboriginal Nations in the BC interior. The issues of "whose economy," "who decides" and "who controls" are central not only for Aboriginal Nations but also for the working class.

Return to top


Brief Review of BC Mining

Most of BC lies within the Western Cordillera, a geological zone known to contain a wide variety of valuable minerals. The complex geological history of BC has provided the province with a rich and varied mineral endowment.

Over the past three decades, the production of minerals has significantly increased due to technological advances in exploration and mining, new domestic and foreign markets and higher prices. BC produces and exports copper, coal, gold, zinc, molybdenum, silver, lead and a growing variety of other industrial and structural minerals. Since 2001, twelve metal and coal mines have opened or reopened in BC. Statistics Canada reports the value of mineral sales in BC more than doubled over the last 7 years reaching $6.6 billion in 2008, up from $2.9 billion in 2001. Investment in mineral exploration was nearly $367 million in 2008, a 1,266 per cent increase over the 2001 investment level of $29 million. Exploration stage projects for minerals, coal, industrial minerals and aggregates totalled 388 throughout BC in 2008 with the number having budgets in excess of $1 million reaching 98. Sixty per cent of Canadian exploration companies are based in BC. They raised $2.9 billion in equity capital for mining and exploration in 2008. That year, there were 10 metal mines, nine coal mines, and more than 35 major industrial minerals quarries and mines in operation in more than 50 BC communities. Approximately 28,000 workers such as miners, electricians, mechanics, machinists, geologists and engineers work to transform ore into useable minerals.

The upsurge of the mining industry in BC during a period of crisis in the forest industry, especially its manufacturing sector, highlights a negative trend to turn Canada into a source of raw materials and a captured market for imported manufactured goods. Mining does not support a diverse stable self-reliant manufacturing sector either in BC or in the rest of Canada. Ownership and control of mining reside in the hands of the international financial oligarchy and are mostly annexed into the U.S. Empire. This imperialist control has an agenda narrowly centred on return on investment for owners of capital not on the interests and needs of BC's economy and its people.  Ownership and control of mining and the precious natural wealth mine workers produce are not in the hands of BC workers and Aboriginal Nations, which is a contradiction that workers and their allies and Aboriginal Nations must resolve.

Owners of mining capital exert enormous economic and political power in BC. For example, the Liberal Party in power in Victoria approved Taseko Mines' irrational proposal to destroy Fish Lake under pressure from the imperialist "gold fever" of owners of capital who have become even more desperate and reckless than usual with the price of gold reaching $1,400 per ounce. Monopoly ownership, power and control also extend over mining communities and the thinking of mine workers, as their livelihoods depend on continued and extended mining production. An independent working class view on mining and a self-reliant economy rooted in diverse manufacturing comes into conflict with many community members who are pressured or even terrorized into a narrow short-term capital-centred outlook on mining. This retrogressive perspective pursues imperialist projects no matter what the cost to the human factor, environment, right to be of Aboriginal Nations and the sovereignty and long-term economic security of Canadians.

Return to top


Discussion on Nation-Building

The Necessity to Restrict Monopoly Right
to Control and Manipulate Prices
Proposal for a Modern Formula to Determine Prices of Production

TML is posting below Part Three of "Discussion on Nation Building -- The Necessity to Restrict Monopoly Right." Part Two was published in TML Daily, November 24, 2010 - No. 201. Part One was published in TML Daily, November 23, 2010 - No. 200.

Part Three
How the Problem of Prices of Production Poses Itself

The working class must investigate and take stern measures to defend itself and society, and solve the problem of prices of production under monopoly capitalism. To find a solution to this problem has become a pressing necessity for a Workers' Opposition. This can be seen in the monopoly prices for pharmaceuticals that threaten to bankrupt and wreck the national health system. The problem poses itself as one of mass political mobilization to put the working class in motion behind its own program, a program that it discusses, develops, adopts as its own and fights for with conviction.

A tendency within the capitalist system towards a falling rate of profit exerts unconscious pressure on owners of monopoly capital to manipulate prices to overcome this tendency. However, by doing so they cause harm to the socialized economy and the people's interests such as can be readily seen with pharmaceutical prices. In response to the $25.1 billion total Canadian market price for prescription drugs in 2008, the Centre for Policy Alternatives (CPA) suggests savings can be found by folding all existing pharmaceutical plans into a universal public drug plan. CPA writes:

"The premiums for such plans (private drug insurance plans) soared by 15% annually between 2003 and 2005, while drug costs rose 8% a year. The reason for the steep rise in premiums is simple: most of the private drug plans are managed by insurance companies which are usually compensated in the form of a percentage of expenditures. As a result, their financial incentive is not to try to stem the growing costs, but to increase them. Also, private drug plans' formularies welcome all new expensive drugs even if they are no more beneficial to patients than cheaper existing drugs.

"Private insurance is clearly less efficient in terms of administrative costs. The administrative fees for public plans in Ontario and Quebec were estimated at 2%, whereas they were 8% for private plans. In total health spending, Canada's public program had administrative costs of 1.3% compared to costs of 13.2% for private plans. We can conservatively infer that at least 6% of costs for drug insurance coverage could be saved if this coverage were provided by a universal Pharmacare program, which would have resulted in savings of $560 million per year.

"Private insurance plans receive tax subsidies on the order of 10% of their expenditures. Every year, about $933 million in tax subsidies could be recovered through a universal Pharmacare program.

"Private drug insurance plans also pay more for drugs than public plans, especially in the case of generics, because of the public plans' superior bargaining power. The private plans usually pay 7% more for generic drugs and 10% more for nonpatented brand-name drugs. Private drug plans normally reimburse for any type of drug without making any pharmaco-economic assessment of cost-efficiency."

(See CPA's proposal Universal Pharmacare for Canada: Costs and Benefits of Publicly Funded Universal Drug Coverage at their website http://policyalternatives.ca.)

This proposal is worthy of discussion, especially on the social front of extending drug coverage to every Canadian. The weakness is the unwillingness to confront monopoly right over the control of prices. Without conscious public control over prices, Canadian Medicare will remain a source of super profits for the drug and hospital supply monopolies, whose egocentric greed may very well bankrupt and wreck our public healthcare program. The projected savings with the proposed universal drug plan mostly come from reductions in administration costs and not from lower prices. The plan still leaves prices of production and market prices of drugs almost entirely in the hands of the global pharmaceutical monopolies. The Workers' Opposition should discuss a more comprehensive program to mobilize the people to take public control in a conscious manner of not only drug prices but all prices at the wholesale level. This could be done in concert with other measures such as changing the tax system, establishing not-for-profit public financial, pharmaceutical and other enterprises, imposing control over the movement of capital in and out of the country, and restricting both the use of third party currencies in international trade and trading of the Canadian dollar. The key issue is that these problems in the economy should be addressed and discussed without prejudice through acts of conscious participation in finding out. The Workers' Opposition should propose solutions to these pricing and other problems that stem from the type of economic system Canadians have inherited. For example, a proposal to renew the tax system would have most government claims made at the point of production in conjunction with Statistics Canada and Revenue Canada establishing prices of production at every major employer in the country. If this were done, all individual taxation such as sales and income taxes, payroll deductions and user fees for public services could be abolished while making a greater amount of social product available for social programs, public services and the general interests of society. A proposal for renewal of the taxation system is discussed in more detail in Part Four of this series.

People should not confine their thinking to what is acceptable to the monopolies and neoliberalism before they start investigation and discussion of this problem of monopoly prices or any other problem for that matter. Most intellectuals and organizations of the middle strata when dealing with economic questions unfortunately begin from a premise that is capital-centred and under the dictate of monopoly right. They conciliate with monopoly control of the economy and consequently end up discussing policy objectives within a very narrow parameter that does not restrict monopoly right or touch the basic interests of the rich, their monopolies and their dictatorship over Canada's economic and political affairs. A regressive habit has been inculcated into the brains of many Canadians to conciliate with monopoly right and hope to find harmony within the capitalist system where no harmony exists, only contradictions and conflict. The issue is to resolve contradictions through struggle to open a door to progress and not conciliate with those powerful forces that continually block solutions and alternatives from being discussed let alone coming into being.

The problem of prices of production revolves around the constant effort of owners of monopoly capital to reverse the tendency towards a lower rate of profit from increased productivity. This tendency is established by history in the transition from petty production to mass industrial production. Owners of capital try every means to reverse this tendency set by history. Their self-serving efforts disrupt the economy, and intensify and prolong economic crises. Some examples of these efforts to reverse the tendency include: manipulation of prices of production and market prices; schemes for big scores through manipulation of sectors of the economy including importantly the financial system; forcing concessions from workers through lowering their overall standard of living; intensifying and lengthening the working day; permanent mass unemployment that increases competition among workers for available work; manipulation of currencies; stoking war fever and spending on military preparations; and significantly, using the pooled public resources of the state to guarantee profits that defy the tendency of a falling rate through pay the rich schemes such as government subsidies, guaranteed contracts, public infrastructure for private companies, low corporate taxes and other means.

In opposition, the working class should welcome the falling rate of profit as normal and part of the transitory system preparing conditions for the new. This tendency of a falling rate of return on investment or falling rate of profit should be allowed to play its historic role. A falling rate of profit is an important spontaneous factor to end capitalist profit on social product and bring into being something qualitatively new. This new profit could be characterized as socialist profit, which is not the preserve of individuals claiming profit of enterprise, interest, fees, rent or executive compensation. It essentially serves to extend reproduction of the socialized economy at the level of the enterprise. Socialist profit is available to enhance productivity at the workplace through mobilization of the human factor and the application of science and technology and to extend cooperation of particular enterprises with other enterprises and the socialized economy as a whole. Socialist profit is distinct from the claims of government (taxation), which are necessary to defend the general interests of society and guarantee the rights of all. Claims of workers and government should be taken from revenue before profit is established and claimed. (A proposed modern formula for setting prices of production and a general rate of profit is discussed in Parts Six and Seven of this series.)

Brief Note on Use-Value versus Exchange-Value

Productivity enhances the contradiction between use-value and exchange-value, which is the root of the tendency for a falling rate of profit. Use-value grows both in quantity and quality as petty production crumbles before the advance of mass industrial production and the increasing application of science and technology to all aspects of the socialized economy. Use-value grows in the form of products and services as exchange-value falls in relative value. The mass of products and services and their use-value constantly increase while their relative exchange-value continually falls. This spontaneous process intensifies the tendency towards a falling rate of profit as the socialized economy conquers all vestiges of petty production and the concentration of ownership becomes global.

The total use-value expressed in available products and services grows while their relative exchange-value falls. This is a spontaneous gravitation of the modern economy of mass industrial production towards socialism and the gradual victory of use-value over exchange-value especially the most important use-value -- human beings and their capacity to work and be productive.

Monopoly right and the old relations of production based on private ownership of competing centres of capital try to block this spontaneous gravitation towards a system under the control of socialized humanity. They devise scheme after scheme for big scores to increase through monopoly right the exchange-value of those commodities under their control, and disrupt and violate the tendency towards a falling rate of profit and the law of value. This results in more severe and prolonged economic crises and seemingly irrational practices such as the wrecking of manufacturing and mass unemployment where millions of workers are not allowed to create social product because owners of capital cannot transform it into exchange-value. Canadians should grasp the truth of the capitalist system that previous production in the form of factories, mills, mines, buildings and machines does not exist to serve workers as means for new production of social wealth. Under this system dominated by monopoly capital, workers serve those factories, mills, mines, machines etc., as a means to multiply the exchange-value and social wealth of the owners of capital. If exchange-value cannot be multiplied, the owners of capital will destroy previous production and let workers sit idle.

The Workers' Opposition through restricting monopoly right can consciously allow to play its historical role the spontaneous gravitation of the economy towards resolving the contradiction between use-value and exchange-value. By exercising control and decision-making over the socialized economy, the Workers' Opposition could organize increasing amounts of products, especially those produced within Department One of the socialized economy destined as means of production, to be transferred within the Canadian economy according to cooperation and agreement without the necessity of transforming their use-value into exchange-value. As well, through increased investments in social programs, those products within Department Two, which are destined as articles of consumption or services would be increasingly available socially according to need through social programs and public services and not have to be turned into exchange-value.

Resolving the contradiction between use-value and exchange-value of the human factor requires eliminating the existence of human beings as commodities for sale on the capitalist labour market and its replacement with a free association of the actual producers. A free association of workers would uphold as paramount the use-value of every worker and take measures to eliminate its negation as exchange-value.

***

Karl Marx explains the two departments of social production:

II. The Two Departments of Social Production

The total product, and therefore the total production, of society may be divided into two major departments:

I. Means of Production, commodities having a form in which they must, or at least may, pass into productive consumption.

II. Articles of Consumption, commodities having a form in which they pass into the individual consumption of the capitalist and the working-class.

All the various branches of production pertaining to each of these two departments form one single great branch of production, that of the means of production in the one case, and that of articles of consumption in the other. The aggregate capital employed in each of these two branches of production constitutes a separate large department of the social capital.

In each department the capital consists of two parts:

1) Variable Capital. This capital, so far as its value is concerned, is equal to the value of the social labour-power employed in this branch of production; in other words, it is equal to the sum of the wages paid for this labour-power. So far as its substance is concerned, it consists of the labour-power in action, i.e., of the living labour set in motion by this capital-value.

2) Constant Capital. This is the value of all the means of production employed for productive purposes in this branch. These, again, are divided into fixed capital, such as machines, instruments of labour, buildings, labouring animals, etc., and circulating constant capital, such as materials of production: raw and auxiliary materials, semi-finished products, etc.

The value of the total annual product created with the aid of this capital in each of the two departments consists of one portion, which represents the constant capital "C" consumed in the process of production and only transferred to the product in accordance with its value, and of another portion added by the entire labour of the year. This latter portion (added by the entire labour of the year) is divided in turn into the replacement of the advanced variable capital "V" (wages, benefits and pensions) and the excess over and above it, which forms the surplus-value "S" (profit of enterprise, interest and rent, and government claims as taxation). And just as the value of every individual commodity, that of the entire annual product of each department consists of C + V + S.

- Karl Marx: Capital, Volume II, Chapter 20: Simple Reproduction, Part 1 #2 (emphases and words in parentheses added)

(Next: Part Four -- Taxation or Claims of Government on Social Product)

Return to top


Read The Marxist-Leninist Daily
Website:  www.cpcml.ca   Email:  editor@cpcml.ca